26 March, 2010

Mitigating Loan Diversion in Housing Microfinance

In Housing Microfinance is More Than Microfinance, I inferred that housing microfinance without a housing outcome is not housing microfinance at all. How do you ensure that housing microfinance results in a tangible improvement to housing? This is a practical question that is at the core of housing microfinance product design and implementation.

The means by which a financial service provider approaches the conversion of housing microfinance into housing purposes is often reflective of its overall  housing paradigm and the extent to which it feels comfortable controlling the customer’s housing process. There are a wide variety of methods to mitigate the risk of a housing microfinance product being diverted to non-housing purposes. Each method has its own pros, cons, risks and implications for reaching scale when the product is implemented. I will briefly look at seven methods of mitigating diversion and promoting a successful conversion of housing microfinance into home improvement. There are certainly more possibilities, and often combinations of methodologies are used, but the following are a few common examples. I will generally refer to housing microfinance loans, but savings products could also be included.


1. Honour System: Some products are designed without any tangible method for encouraging the finance to housing conversion. A customer presents an application for housing finance, perhaps with a budget or other requirements, and states that the loan will be used for housing. After disbursement, it is simply assumed that the loan was used for its intended purpose. The advantage of this is that it is extremely cost effective and has a low level of management complexity beyond the institution's normal business. Naturally, it can be assumed that some of the "housing" loans are not actually being used for housing. A counter argument is that given the high rate of diversion of business loans into housing activities, it could also be assumed that a large number of loans are being used for housing. If the product can achieve high volume, it might actually serve more customers with their housing needs than a product designed to better ensure the housing finance to housing conversion which has challenges scaling up.

2. Verification of Loan Use: In order to move away from assumptions about how a housing microfinance product is being used, an institution can verify the loan use. This would usually require at least a post-disbursement site visit to see that the proposed loan use activity was carried out. A pre-disbursement visit would improve reliability of the findings, to ensure that the customer does not show work that was completed long before the loan was even disbursed. Loan use verification simply puts a number to the finance to housing conversion. How many loans or what percentage of loans actually resulted in home improvements? Because there is no penalty or incentive for loan use built in, there is relatively low risk. The cost would be the cost of the verification visit, and the time taken to do it and report.

3. Cost Structure: Verification of loan use can be taken a step further by building in incentives or disincentives into the product’s cost structure based on loan use. The proposed housing project is inspected before the loan is disbursed and then again after disbursement. An incentive or penalty is then applied based on loan use. In my work in Uganda and Tanzania, we have disbursed loans at higher than market rate interest. If the loan is verified as having been used for housing purposes, it is then discounted to market rate or slightly below market rate. This seems to have a positive effect in curbing diversion. There are some risks and costs associated with this method. There is a possibility of collusion between the customer and staff to declare a loan verified as having been used for its intended purpose (when it was actually diverted) in order to receive a lower interest rate. Related costs include the cost of the visits as well as the administrative costs of changing repayment schedules, reporting and internal controls.

4. Multiple Disbursements: Multiple disbursements are another popular means of promoting the finance to housing conversion. This might also be thought of as “loan use verification in stages.” Rather than disbursing the entire loan at once, customers are given the loan in tranches and work is verified as a pre-requisite for the next disbursement. This limits the risk of diversion to the first disbursement only, rather than the entire loan amount. There is still a risk of collusion between customer and staff as with the cost structure methodology. The cost of verification is higher that the verification of cost structure methods, because of multiple visits to the site. There are more administrative tasks and financial transactions involved with the multiple disbursements

5. Site Supervision: Site supervision as a means of mitigating loan use diversion assumes that a key problem is poor use of materials, rather than mal-intent. It is sometimes thought of as a means of ensuring that housing finance results in a house, but it tends to be more of a quality control response than mitigation of outright diversion. On its own, there is little risk if it is not associated with a penalty or incentive for loan use. The only risk may be that of Turner's Third Law of Housing, should the customer be unhappy with the supervision and result. Associated costs include multiple visits and technical staff sufficient to support the product at scale. Site supervision can easily be linked to other methodologies that are more effective at mitigating actual diversion of funds, such as multiple disbursements or in-kind service.

6. Materials / Services In-Kind: The challenge of the finance-housing conversion is that cash is fungible and a loan designated for housing can just as easily be applied to something else. By providing materials or building services in-kind, it greatly decreases the likelihood that the loan will be diverted to non-housing purposes. This method could be an arrangement with a supplier through which the customer collects the materials needed, or it could be procurement by the lender. Procurement adds numerous risks of fraud. Kickbacks from suppliers are common and prices can be manipulated. This method has increased management complexity, especially when the requisite internal controls needs are taken into consideration. Turner’s Third Law may also be experienced if customers perceive that they have been provided with materials that are either more expensive or of a quality different than what they would have chosen on their own.

7. Full Service Delivery: One of the most certain ways to ensure a finance-housing conversion in housing microfinance is to control the housing process and deliver the service in full. The financial service provider essentially becomes a general contractor or linked to an outsourced general contractor-type service. This an effective but expensive and management intensive method of preventing loan diversion and ensuring the housing outcome. It has multiple risks throughout the process that must be mitigated with internal controls. Due to the intensive nature of the services provided, this methodology is the most challenging to operate at scale.

Each method has its pros and cons. Some appear to mitigate diversion better, but with  added risks, costs and management complexity. As cost, risk and complexity increase, the product will be more difficult to deliver at scale, especially for financial providers without construction experience. Choices are made along the way of developing a product. Is it better to offer services at high volume and acknowledge that some housing loans are diverted to non-housing purposes, or to tightly control the process and significantly decrease diversion even if it is at the cost of volume and the number of customers served?

No method completely eliminates diversion if the product is delivered at scale. I have personally experienced cases of “ghost houses” even where materials were provided in-kind in a full service delivery package. How the finance to housing conversion is approached, however, continues to be perhaps the critical consideration in housing microfinance design. Which trade-offs will be made and why? The institution's approach microfinance linked with its housing paradigm are likely to be the guiding factors in making the decision.

20 March, 2010

Housing Microfinance Is More Than Microfinance

In Housing Microfinance is Microfinance Part 1 and Part 2, I proposed that the most effective housing microfinance in terms of breadth and depth will conform closely to the key principles of microfinance. Housing microfinance may, however, be subject to influences that could either cause it to go “up market” or make it difficult to recover the costs of delivery. A focus on the double bottom line of profitability and social performance will keep housing microfinance true to the key principles of microfinance and result in the most effective delivery of affordable housing finance to low income households. Housing microfinance is indeed microfinance, but at the same time it is also more than microfinance. It is a specialty product that seeks specific housing outcomes.

Housing microfinance targets improved housing in one form or another. It may be to build or improve the customer’s home or it could be applied to rental units that increase the customers’ income while providing rental accommodation for others. A product or service may be marketed as housing microfinance and bear the words home improvement, but without a housing result it is not housing microfinance. A housing microfinance product that does not have a mechanism for ensuring that the financial service is applied to housing is in practice little more than an ordinary consumption loan. Such housing microfinance products do exist and in some places it is possible to obtain a “home improvement loan” to finance a motorcycle, business, school fees or other.
The microfinance industry has long acknowledged that it is not uncommon for business loans to be diverted to home improvement purposes. Clients who use microfinance services tend to be quite savvy. When a housing microfinance product has terms and conditions that are even marginally more favourable than other products, there is an equal likelihood of a housing microfinance service being diverted to non-housing purposes. This may or may not be problem for the financial institution, depending on their commitment to the housing outcome, but it makes the different between a personal loan or savings product and housing microfinance.

Balancing the housing outcome of a loan against the double bottom line that is implicit in microfinance principles is not an easy task. Too much cost on the housing component of the product could threaten either the ability to deliver a commercially viable financial product or push the product away from the reach of the poor. At the same time, diversion to non-housing purposes is very likely without sufficient emphasis on ensuring a housing outcome.
There are many ways to mitigate diversion of housing microfinance services to non-housing purposes. To have a housing microfinance product that can reach significant scale and continue to serve low income households, the methods for mitigating diversion should support the double bottom line while ensuring a housing outcome. In my next post I will look various methodologies in the battle against loan diversion. How do you turn a housing microfinance service into a housing outcome?


06 March, 2010

Housing Microfinance is Microfinance: Part 2

In Housing Microfinance: A Guide to Practice, Franck Daphnis gives an excellent general description of what we could expect in a housing microfinance product:
From a microfinance product perspective, housing microfinance encompasses financial services that allow poor and low-income clients to finance their habitat needs with methodologies adapted from the microfinance revolution. These methodologies rest most notably on the following principles: (1) Loans are for relatively small amounts and are based on the clients’ capacity to repay; (2) Repayment periods are relatively short (especially compared to mortgage lending) and are on a par with mid- to high-end microfinance individual loans; (3) Loan pricing is expected to cover the real, long-run costs – operational and financial – of providing the service; (4) Loans are not heavily collateralized, if at all, and collateral substitutes are often used; (5) Loans tend to finance habitat needs incrementally, a function of the purchasing power of loans with short repayment periods and relatively low monthly payments; and (6) If the provider is an MFI, credit services for housing can be linked to prior participation in savings or more traditional microenterprise loan services. In summary, from a product-based perspective, housing microfinance is the “micro financing” of housing needs: the application of a microfinance-based approach to housing finance.[1]

Daphnis’ explanation clearly makes the case for housing microfinance as microfinance, inclusive of the low income target group and the key features and principles. He  demonstrates how an incremental approach to housing finance is a natural function of the product features and the target group’s capacity to pay. (Not to mention that it fits with how low income households typically build their homes.) Daphnis also highlights pricing for sustainability (covering the real, long-run costs), which is one of the Key Principles of Microfinance as indentified by CGAP. One would expect a housing microfinance service to bear the hallmarks of microfinance and work within its key principles. Perhaps more than other microfinance products, however, housing microfinance may be subject to influences that potentially challenge its ability to stand as a strong microfinance product and practice.

In Housing Microfinance is Microfinance: Part 1, I stated that the differentiating factors in how much microfinance is in a given housing microfinance product derive from how the “housing” component is approached and its effect on the product features. Where the leadership of institution falls on the housing paradigm continuum (see: Housing Paradigms and Housing Microfinance) influences how it will design its housing microfinance services and quite possibly the extent to which they will align with the general principles of microfinance. Those who align with the provider paradigm of housing are likely to emphasize the house as the product, which can easily influence the design and delivery of the financial service.

Several tendencies will increase the likelihood that an institution’s housing microfinance services will closely align with the principles of microfinance: 1) An emphasis on demand-driven products that are affordable to poor and low income households; 2) A drive to achieve a double bottom line of profitability linked with social performance; 3) Defining the provision housing finance itself as a legitimate housing activity; 4) Understanding housing to be a process (housing as a verb); 5) An acceptance of local, often informal, channels for housing provision; and 6) A belief that low income households can and should be the decision makers in and drivers of their housing process.

A tendency to view housing as a noun could decrease the likelihood that an institution’s housing microfinance service will closely align with the microfinance principles and practices. Housing is expensive. When the emphasis shifts from the finance as a product to the house as the product, the potential for greatly increased cost of product delivery is very real. This can result in a difficult balancing act between affordability (for low income households), the cost of the service / the loan amount and sustainability. How well an institution balances these will become evident when crunching the numbers associated with the double bottom line and taking a close look at who is benefitting from the service: How are the ratios (OSS, FSS, Return on Investment, etc)? How is the social performance rating? How is the portfolio performance?

Developing financial products that are both affordable and sustainable is a challenge in its own right. Added costs related to meeting the institution’s housing standards magnify this challenge for housing microfinance. This frequently (although not always) results in at least one of the three following scenarios:
1. Moving the Target: Who doesn’t want to show a nice, beautiful house on their housing microfinance brochures or their reports to the board of directors, shareholders or providers of capital? What is one way to maintain profitability while being able to ensure that houses are of high standards? Serve clients of higher incomes. Housing microfinance can go upmarket very quickly and even start to bear a suspicious resemblance to mortgage financing. When assessing the double bottom line, social performance may be weak if the house is emphasized over affordability. If the housing loans are expensive and the product is still commercially viable, this could move the housing microfinance product away from one of the objectives of microfinance: To serve poor and low income households with financial services.


2. Subsidizing the Target: How do you serve poor and low income households with a high quality housing product that may be beyond their capacity to repay? Subsidize it! Most institutions use the language of sustainability, but the truth about an institution’s sustainability will be in the ratios, not the promotional materials. It is possible to offer a housing microfinance product and talk about sustainability in general terms without ever having a viable plan to at least break even. A reliance on subsidy to deliver housing services moves away from operationalal and  financial sustainability - a key principle of microfinance.
3. Extending the Loan Period: How do you provide a high quality house as a product to low income households without subsidy? Adjust the product features! One way of making housing microfinance affordable would be to extend the loan period to make it more like a mortgage. This seems like a reasonable idea on the surface, but when applied to low income households it eventually degenerates into portfolio health problems. Microfinance loans tend to be relatively short and there are good reasons for this.

The added cost burden (to either the client or the insitution) of relatively expensive housing support services or high loan amounts can easily either force product features away from microfinance norms or move the product away from accepted key principles of microfinance.  All of this is not to say that a housing microfinance product that includes housing support services will necessarily be something other than microfinance. Where there is an effective demand for such services from poor and low income households, it makes sense to offer them. Housing microfinance does, however, open itself up to housing ideologies that may create a supply-side push of non-financial services tied to a housing microfinance product. That could make achieving the double bottom line and conforming closely to the principles of microfinance significantly more challenging. In the absence of significant captial to make the push, such products will face difficulty in achieving scale and having significant impact on the financial landscape in Sub-Saharan Africa, where housing microfinance is just starting to develop and informal systems of housing and housing finance are the norm.

Housing microfinance is microfinance. Housing microfinance products that go upmarket and are priced above the affordability level of the poor will almost always fail to conform to the principles of microfinance, which include both serving low income households and sustainability. Broad access to affordable housing finance in Africa will likely only be achieved through a prevalence of housing microfinance products that closely conform to the principles of microfinance (running parallel with a stronger mortgage market). The extent that this can be done with a significant amount of non-financial housing services tied to the product will depend on the true effective demand for those services from the poor more than the housing ideologies of the service providers. How much microfinance is in a given housing microfinance product? The numbers will eventually tell the story.

[1] Daphnis, F. &; Ferugson, B. (2004). Housing Microfinance: A guide to Practice. Bloomfield, CT: Kumarian Press, p. 4.